Two Plus Two Newer Archives  

Go Back   Two Plus Two Newer Archives > Two Plus Two > Two Plus Two Internet Magazine
FAQ Community Calendar Today's Posts Search

Reply
 
Thread Tools Display Modes
  #11  
Old 09-08-2006, 10:57 PM
ptmusic ptmusic is offline
Senior Member
 
Join Date: Mar 2005
Location: Need MBA-level finance job!
Posts: 1,855
Default Re: Terror in Poker and Finance Part II

I guess I'd rather be Player 1 also. As long as my bankroll was sufficiently large that risk of ruin was minimal. Otherwise, a slight increase in EV along with a relatively greater increase in SD implies that the risk outweighs the benefits (and I'd rather be Player 2 in that spot).
Reply With Quote
  #12  
Old 09-09-2006, 02:47 AM
Off Duty Off Duty is offline
Senior Member
 
Join Date: Jan 2006
Location: OC
Posts: 544
Default Re: Terror in Poker and Finance Part II

Is it possible? Yes.

Is it likely? Maybe.

Maybe player two is super talented with some huge holes and could smoke player one in EV and SD. Never consider the best of both worlds as an unattainable option.

Variance is a bitch, and some of us will do a lot to stay away from it if it doesn't mess with our EV much and it tends to help keep us off of tilt.
Reply With Quote
  #13  
Old 09-09-2006, 10:17 PM
flight2q flight2q is offline
Senior Member
 
Join Date: Jul 2005
Location: waking up with cowboys
Posts: 379
Default Re: Terror in Poker and Finance Part II

[ QUOTE ]
I'm sorry, I don't see it. You claim, "The object is to get your maximize your return to standard deviation ratio, thus maximizing your Sharpe ratio," but that is not correct. The object is to make the most money.

[/ QUOTE ]

Right. Don't let these guys fool you, Sweet. Poker differs from finance, because your time is inherently consumed playing poker, and EV can go down very quickly if you try to play higher stakes.

Where is the feedback in the formula? If the author had shown how the EV of the game adjusted (and hence the Sharpe ratio) as a result of making -EV decisions, that would have been some new material. There would still be lots of issues, but that would probably be sufficient to drive home the only real point - people playing on short bankrolls have extra incentive to avoid wacko tables, because variance reducing play at those tables does not really help.
Reply With Quote
  #14  
Old 09-10-2006, 11:59 PM
Dan Mezick Dan Mezick is offline
Junior Member
 
Join Date: Sep 2006
Posts: 6
Default Re: Terror in Poker and Finance Part II

I am very pleased that my second article sparks real debate about evaluating poker plays and actions on a risk-adjusted, Sharpe-ratio basis, rather than EV alone.

I like this thread a lot and I sincerely thank the OP, Sweet, for opening it up.

I admit that I may be 100%, completely dead wrong in my beliefs about the merits of Sharpe ratio relative to EV.

Will I ever have to? Probably not. We’ll see.

What I’m really looking for is for the best thinkers on 2+2 to enter this discussion.



Generally speaking, I am very surprised that so few readers are not deeply offended by, and rabidly opposed to, my assertion that EV alone is NOT the best basis for totally evaluating a given poker situation.

The second sentence of the essay challenges the the reader’s beliefs about EV right from the start:

“Poker plays are best evaluated on a risk-adjusted basis, rather than simply considering Expected Value alone.”

Don’t you find it kind of interesting that so few 2+2 readers are actually challenging this statement?

Here is another one: at the end of the article, I throw down this bald assertion:

“The player with the better Sharpe Ratio is the better player. He makes more money per unit of bankroll on a risk-adjusted basis. It can be said that he deploys capital better, by managing risk more effectively.”




Finance guys know for a fact that Sharpe ratio, Sortino ratio and other reward/risk ratios have EVERYTHING to do with the proper evaluation of poker games, starting poker hands and individual poker plays. That’s because every poker situation is, at the core, financial in nature.

Sharpe ratio and its derivatives are being used to the best players, now, to make plays that increase reward per unit of risk, or lower risk per unit of reward, or both.

Risk has many components, and some are hard to measure or even identify. For example, highly volatile returns tend to trigger emotions and ultimately, real “tilt” in some players. Self-aware players identify and manage that risk. In practical terms, this “tilt risk” adds an additional dimension of risk to the denominator of the reward-to-risk (Sharpe) ratio for certain kinds of plays. My point is that risk has many components, and that some of these risks may be difficult to measure. But, to correctly figure the risk-adjusted value of any poker action, you must sincerely **try** to quantify ALL the components of risk—and reward.

Reward also has many components, some of which are non-cash but convertible to cash by highly skilled players. For example, a given play can gain you some bluff-equity, even if you lose the hand. That is a very real component of reward that a skilled player always considers. Recognizing the potential gain in bluff-equity makes some otherwise marginal moves very playable. This is because the value of the potential bluff-equity gained increases the theoretical reward, relative to the theoretical risk. This is Sharpe applied to poker.

Bluff-equity is a component of “overall theoretical reward” the same way propensity-to-tilt is a component of “overall theoretical risk”. Both of these are examples of non-cash rewards and risks inherent in a given play. Both must be included when thinking about the risk-adjusted (Sharpe ratio) value of a given play. Thinking about poker theory in terms of Sharpe provides a framework for a more quantitative, non-discretionary approach to the game. Discussing poker in terms of Sharpe provides rigor and a framework for explaining the reasoning behind complex poker decision making.

I often hear the answer “it depends” to questions about many poker problems. Depends on what, exactly? In my view, it almost always depends on the risk-adjusted quality of the play after all of the rewards and all the risks, cash and non-cash, have been identified, considered and weighed. Sharpe ratio and its derivatives (such as Sortino) provide a framework for discussing complex poker problems quantitatively. Sharpe is just a starting point. We have a long way to go in terms of advancing the state of the art in poker theory.

Finance and especially the Modern Portfolio Theory (MPT) can help get us there.

I assert that, if you choose to turn a blind eye to Sharpe and continue to play by EV alone, you are sure to be taking the worst of it relative to opponents who truly understand how to apply Sharpe’s work to poker.
Reply With Quote
  #15  
Old 09-11-2006, 01:12 AM
JaredL JaredL is offline
Senior Member
 
Join Date: Jan 2004
Location: No te olvidamos
Posts: 10,851
Default Re: Terror in Poker and Finance Part II

I don't fully understand a lot of this discussion as I have no background in finance, but here is my view.

Suppose a particular high variance play in my arsenal slightly increases my EV. Taking it out of my game would lead to a lower variance and a greater sharpe ratio. Taking only one move into account here it's not going to change either by much, but there are probably several such plays.

Let's do some simple cost/benefit analysis. The benefits seem to be:

1. Decreasing my variance by adjusting my play would allow me to play in higher stakes games at my given bankroll.
2. At a given bankroll I'm less likely to have a severe downswing leading to me going bust and/or having to move down.

However, the cost is that you lose EV at the current game you're in. Another cost is that you probably will learn more as a player by making these high variance plays.

Let's study them individually.

1. Ability to move up

The span of possible games is not continuous so 1 may not be a factor. For example, considering my bankroll it may be possible for me to move up from 5/10 to 5.5/11 by lowering my EV and decreasing my variance but such a game doesn't exist. Furthermore, given my skill level if I had an infinite bankroll 5/10 may be a higher EV game (obviously infinitely rolled EV is the only consideration) than the next actual available level. In fact, many players are playing in the game that gives them the highest expected earn.

2. This could be a factor. However, many players are overbankrolled for the highest EV game available to them. For these people, this isn't. Furthermore, if people are in a situation where losing money could force them to go down it is very likely that they will do as you suggest and give up +EV but high variance plays. There are books, IIRC one of them is Greenstein's AotR, that suggest playing conservatively if going on a downswing means you have to drop in stakes.

So in short, your theory only applies to people that are slightly to moderately underbankrolled for the highest EV game available to them. Note that this would exclude stakes where people are ridiculously underrolled for their best game.
Reply With Quote
  #16  
Old 09-11-2006, 07:00 AM
Dan Mezick Dan Mezick is offline
Junior Member
 
Join Date: Sep 2006
Posts: 6
Default Re: Terror in Poker and Finance Part II

JaredL,

Thanks for your highly detailed post. You describe and bring up financial points in conversational English, and you know PLENTY about these topics. One of the issues about these topics is the lack of sufficient terminology we have to discuss them. Precise terms helps with generating collaborative discussion and can advance any art or science, such as poker theory. We are hobbled by a lack of precise terminology. Finance helps because the terminology is there to speak with precision. This is one of the main points of my article series.

The main point you raise is the potential error of giving up +EV when the BR size is sufficient. This is true, especially (as you point out) when the range of opportunities is for sizing variance to the BR (via bet/stakes sizing) are not ideal. I must agree with you here.

Remember though, I am speaking in highly theoretical terms. My basic theoretical premises are sound; adjustments to theory must fit the situation in practice. You make a key point about adjusting that does not invalidate my poker theory thesis about Sharpe.

Secondly you raise many points about the complex interrelationships between Sharpe, EV, variance and RoR. My article series is ALL about these poker issues, spoken in financial terminology and using financial concepts.

Lastly, in terms of the potential error of giving up +EV assuming a BR that can enforce acceptable RoR, I believe that in general most players are underrolled and that most players take on massive quantities of "uncompensated volatility" when they play poker.

Thanks again for your posted reply. It is sure to attract more interest to 'Poker and Finance'.



Links:

Uncompensated Volatility
"One way to control risk drag would be to eliminate volatility entirely. But doing so provides a hollow victory because..."
Reply With Quote
  #17  
Old 09-11-2006, 08:33 AM
Izverg04 Izverg04 is offline
Senior Member
 
Join Date: Mar 2004
Posts: 308
Default Re: Terror in Poker and Finance Part II

[ QUOTE ]

The second sentence of the essay challenges the the reader’s beliefs about EV right from the start:

“Poker plays are best evaluated on a risk-adjusted basis, rather than simply considering Expected Value alone.”

[/ QUOTE ]

This statement is trivial and useless in practice at the same time. Dan, how much would you guess someone would lose, in terms of expected utility, if he played in a way that perfectly maximized expected value instead of expected utility? Would it be 1% of the winrate? 2%? Now how much do you think a typical expert player loses because he doesn't maximize his return (makes mistakes)?


[ QUOTE ]
“The player with the better Sharpe Ratio is the better player. He makes more money per unit of bankroll on a risk-adjusted basis. It can be said that he deploys capital better, by managing risk more effectively.”

[/ QUOTE ]
Could you give a numerical example of what you mean? Because using Sharpe ratio in the context of poker really doesn't make sense in any situation I can think of.


[ QUOTE ]
Sharpe ratio and its derivatives are being used to the best players, now, to make plays that increase reward per unit of risk, or lower risk per unit of reward, or both.

[/ QUOTE ]
I think you are inventing a class of poker players that really doesn't exist.

[ QUOTE ]
[...] risk-adjusted (Sharpe ratio) value of a given play.

[/ QUOTE ]
Are you just using "Sharpe ratio" as shorthand for "risk-adjusting expected returns to obtain the expected utility of a gamble"? You are throwing Sharpe and other financial risk measures all over the place, and these are usually specific results to specific risk-adjustment problems that don't come up in the same form anywhere in poker.
Reply With Quote
  #18  
Old 09-11-2006, 08:45 AM
Izverg04 Izverg04 is offline
Senior Member
 
Join Date: Mar 2004
Posts: 308
Default Re: Terror in Poker and Finance Part II

By the way, here is a very simple way, based on Expected Utility theory, to appraise you risk. For small bets (small compared to bankroll), expected utility or the Certainty Equivalent of a play is:

CE=EV-Var/2R,

where EV and Var are expected value and StdDev^2 of a gamble, and R is the Kelly bankroll (equal to e.g. bankroll/4 for Kelly/4 bettors).

Actually, more formally, R is the curvature of your utility function R=-U'(x)/U''(x). I assumed here that R remains about the same whatever the result of the gamble is (thus the caveat about small bets).

No need for fancy ratios from quantitative finance. Find CE for the choices that you have and make the decision that maximizes CE. Most of the time you'll make the same choice as if you were maximizing EV, while taking occasional EV hits in marginal situations, where cost of variance is too high.
Reply With Quote
  #19  
Old 09-15-2006, 02:29 AM
pzhon pzhon is offline
Senior Member
 
Join Date: Mar 2004
Posts: 4,515
Default Re: Terror in Poker and Finance Part II

[ QUOTE ]

Generally speaking, I am very surprised that so few readers are not deeply offended by, and rabidly opposed to, my assertion that EV alone is NOT the best basis for totally evaluating a given poker situation.

[/ QUOTE ]
You are attacking a straw man. The objections people have are not that E$ is the only thing that matters. There are contexts in which a different combination of E$ and risk is more appropriate than the Sharpe ratio. Please don't assume that anyone who disagrees with you is saying that only E$ matters.

The OP pointed out a context in which E$ is much more important than the standard deviation. As your bankroll grows, maximizing E$ is relatively more important than minimizing variance for the purpose of maximizing expected utility. If you are underbankrolled, you may want to be more conservative than the Sharpe ratio would suggest. According to polls, 2+2ers tend to be overbankrolled, so the Sharpe ratio should tend to overemphasize managing risk while underemphasizing E$.

Rather than consider only EV/SD, you can consider (EV^n)/SD. For any n, you get a risk vs. reward ratio, and only n=1 corresponds to the Sharpe ratio. The most appropriate n to use depends on both your Kelly fraction and your bankroll.

There are other objections to the Sharpe ratio, such as that the shape of the distribution of results about the mean matters. To a slightly favorable coinflip, it is possible to add a purely favorable gamble which decreases the Sharpe ratio because it increases the variance much more than it increases the expected value, e.g., a 1/1,000,000 chance to win $10,000 adds a penny to EV, but adds about as much variance as a coin-flip for $100. This might ruin the Sharpe ratio of someone crushing low stakes games, but it would be nothing to fear. Less obviously, buying lottery tickets is not the same as selling lottery tickets.

[ QUOTE ]

“Poker plays are best evaluated on a risk-adjusted basis, rather than simply considering Expected Value alone.”

Don’t you find it kind of interesting that so few 2+2 readers are actually challenging this statement?


[/ QUOTE ]
Not really. Perhaps your expectations are off. You underestimated your audience.

[ QUOTE ]

The player with the better Sharpe Ratio is the better player...

Finance guys know for a fact that Sharpe ratio, Sortino ratio and other reward/risk ratios ...


[/ QUOTE ]
Stop right there. If the Sharpe ratio is everything, why would there be other measures like the Sortino measure? The answer is that the Sharpe ratio isn't everything, which is intuitive for many poker players who don't know the finance terminology. The Sharpe ratio is inappropriate for many situations, such as the one the OP brought up. That strongly suggests that your assertion, that a better Sharpe ratio means you are a better player, is wrong.

[ QUOTE ]

I assert that, if you choose to turn a blind eye to Sharpe and continue to play by EV alone, you are sure to be taking the worst of it relative to opponents who truly understand how to apply Sharpe’s work to poker.

[/ QUOTE ]
You are attacking a straw man. We aren't saying EV is everything. We're saying something more complicated that your assertion that the Sharpe ratio is everything.

It is possible to ignore the Sharpe ratio and not to be taking the worst of it in any serious sense. E$ is roughly zero sum, but variance is not. If I evaluate my risks in a different consistent fashion from the way you do, that doesn't mean I lose, and it doesn't mean you gain from playing me.
Reply With Quote
Reply


Posting Rules
You may not post new threads
You may not post replies
You may not post attachments
You may not edit your posts

BB code is On
Smilies are On
[IMG] code is On
HTML code is Off

Forum Jump


All times are GMT -4. The time now is 07:25 PM.


Powered by vBulletin® Version 3.8.11
Copyright ©2000 - 2024, vBulletin Solutions Inc.